Gender inequality refers to
unequal treatment or perceptions of individuals based on their gender. It
arises from differences in socially constructed gender roles as well as
biologically through chromosomes, brain structure, and hormonal differences.
There are many reasons to be
concerned about existing gender inequalities in important well-being related
dimensions such as education, health, employment, or pay. From a well-being as
well as an equity perspective, such gender inequalities are problematic as they
lower well-being and are a form of injustice in most conceptions of equity or
justice. While such a view would argue for reducing gender inequalities in these
dimensions of well-being on intrinsic grounds, recently a literature has
developed that has investigated the instrumental effects of gender inequality
on other important development outcomes with a particular focus on economic
growth.
The glass ceiling effect is also
considered a possible contributor to the gender wage gap or income disparity.
This effect suggests that gender provides significant disadvantages towards the
top of job hierarchies which become worse as a person’s career goes on. The
term glass ceiling implies that invisible or artificial barriers exist which
prevent women from advancing within their jobs or receiving promotions. These
barriers exist in spite of the achievements or qualifications of the women and
still exist when other characteristics that are job-relevant such as experience,
education, and abilities are controlled for. The inequality effects of the
glass ceiling are more prevalent within higher-powered or higher income
occupations, with fewer women holding these types of occupations. The glass
ceiling effect also indicates the limited chances of women for income raises
and promotion or advancement to more prestigious positions or jobs. As women
are prevented by these artificial barriers from receiving job promotions or
income raises, the effects of the inequality of the glass ceiling increase over
the course of a woman’s career.
Gender inequalities often stem
from social structures that have institutionalized conceptions of gender
differences.
Marginalization occurs on an
individual level when someone feels as if they are on the fringes or margins of
their respective society. This is a social process and displays how current
policies in place can affect people. For example, media advertisements display
young girls with easy bake ovens (promoting being a housewife) as well as with
dolls that they can feed and change the diaper of (promoting being a mother).
When women are not the stereotypical housewife and mother, they have to face
the consequences that come along with that.
Sexism and discrimination
Gender inequality can further be
understood through the mechanisms of sexism. Discrimination takes place in this
manner as men and women are subject to prejudicial treatment on the basis of
gender alone. Sexism occurs when men and women are framed within two dimensions
of social cognition.
Discrimination also plays out
with networking and in preferential treatment within the economic market. Men
typically occupy positions of power within the job economy. Due to taste or
preference for other men because they share similar characteristics, men in
these positions of power are more likely to hire or promote other men, thus
discriminating against women.
Gender Inequality and Economic
Performance: Theory and Evidence
There have been a number of
theoretical and empirical studies finding that gender inequality in education
and employment reduce economic growth. The main arguments from the literature,
which are discussed in detail in Klasen (1999, 2002, 2006) are briefly summarized
below.
Regarding gender inequality in
education, the theoretical literature suggests that such gender inequality reduces
the average amount of human capital in a society and thus harms economic
performance. It does so as by artificially restricting the pool of talent from
which to draw for education and thereby excluding highly qualified girls (and
taking less qualified boys instead, e.g. Dollar and Gatti, 1999).
Moreover, if there are declining
marginal returns to education, restricting the education of girls to lower
levels while taking the education of boys to higher levels means that the marginal
return to educating girls is higher than that of boys and thus would boost
overall economic performance (World Bank 2001; Knowles et al. 2002).
Another argument relates to
externalities of female education. Promoting female education is known to
reduce fertility levels, reduce child mortality levels, and promote the
education of the next generation. Each factor in turn has a positive impact on economic
growth. Thus gender gaps in education reduce the benefits to society of high female
education (e.g. Galor and Weil 1996; Lagerlöf 1999; World Bank 2001; King, Klasen,
and Porter 2008). There is also an important timing issue involved here.
Reduced fertility levels will,
after some twenty years, lead to a favourable demographic constellation which
Bloom and Williamson (1998) refer to as a ‘demographic gift’. For a period of
several decades, the working age population will grow much faster than overall population,
thus lowering dependency rates with positive repercussions for per capita economic
growth.
A third argument relates to
international competitiveness. Many East Asian countries have been able to be
competitive on world markets through the use of femaleintensive export-oriented
manufacturing industries, a strategy that is now finding followers in South
Asia and individual countries across the developing world (e.g. Seguino, 2000a,
b).
No comments:
Post a Comment