The
current global Perception of microfinance
In
the global arena there is already the impression that microfinance is
successful in reducing poverty. Many policy makers are therefore engaged on how
to make microfinance sustainable and available to many poor households in the
future. Many stake holders in the microfinance industry especially donors and
investors argue that, “Microfinance can pay for itself, and must do so if it is
to reach very large numbers of poor households” (CGAP). The overall message in
this argument is that unless microfinance providers charge enough to cover
their costs, they will always be limited by the scarce and uncertain supply of
subsidies from governments and donors. The main underlying assumption in this
argument is that microfinance is already good for the clients, and therefore
what is really urgent is to make the financial service available to as many
poor people as possible. Morduch (2000) correctly points out that this kind of
enthusiasm for microfinance rests on an enticing win-win proposition that:
Microfinance institutions that follow the principles of good banking will also
be the ones that alleviate the most poverty.
The
assumption being that with good banking practices it is possible to cover costs
and operate in a sustainable manner to continue serving clients and alleviating
poverty (Morduch 2000).The “win-win” situation both for the investor and the
poor can be explained as follows: The investor in microfinance programs follows
good banking practices with the possibility of some profit, while the poor
continue to benefit by accessing reliable credit that is assumed to be
beneficial to their welfare. The supporters of the “win- win” proposition
stress (mainly by assumption) that the ability to repay loans by the poor is a good
indicator that whatever investments the poor make with their micro credit loans
must be giving back profits. Given the assumption that microfinance is already
beneficial to the poor, the “win-win” proposition further assumes that the
amount of house hold poverty reduced is directly proportional to the number of
households reached with microfinance.
The
“win-win” vision has been translated in to a series of “best practices” circulated
widely by a number of key donors including the Consultative Group to Assist the
Poorest (CGAP). CGAP is a consortium of NGOs hosted at the World Bank. Other donor
organizations that embrace “best practice microfinance” include, United States Agency
for International Development (USAID) and the United Nations Development programme
(UNDP) among other key donors. It is important to note that the proposal
of a commercial approach to microfinance for the poor has been questioned
by socially oriented service providers. Especially the assumptions underlying
the “win-win” proposition have raised eye brows among socially oriented service
providers who question the validity of such assumptions in the real world.
Justification
Rigorous
empirical analysis in the issue of statistical impact of microfinance began in
the1990s. The studies so far remain few and the results of these studies are
highly provocative. The first school of thought questions the relevance of
microfinance as a poverty reducing policy in the first place. (Adam & Von
Pische, 1992) argued that “debt is not an effective tool for helping most poor
people to enhance their economic condition be they operators of small farms or
micro entrepreneurs”. The main argument of Adam and Von Pische (1992) is that
there are other more important constraints that face small agricultural
households and they include product prices, land tenure, technology, market access
and risk. Also in support of the same view is Gulli (1998) who argues that
credit is not always the main constraint for micro enterprises´ growth and
development, and that poor people demand a wide range of financial, business
development and social services for different business and household purposes.
In a close rejoinder Mayoux (2002) argues that the logical assumption of
virtuous spiral of economic empowerment to the household due to microfinance
does not in reality exist. This is particularly so given that there exists
gender relations in society in relation to loan uses; a scenario that more
often that not leaves poor women borrowers highly indebted, and not much wealth
to show for it (Mayoux 2002).
As
though to counter the negative arguments against the impact of microfinance on poverty
reduction, other studies have found that microfinance is relevant to poverty reduction
not just for the beneficiaries but also there are positive spillover effects to
the rest of the community (Khandker 2006). In his study Khandker (2006) uses a
panel household survey from Bangladesh and observes that access to microfinance
contributes to poverty reduction, especially for female participants, and to
the overall poverty reduction at the village level. Pitt and Khandker (1998)
find, using data from three programs in rural Bangladesh, that borrowing from
group-lending schemes increased consumption of poor households. However,
Morduch 1998b has argued that Pitt and Khandker’s result reflect program
selection effects rather than the impact of borrowing per se.
There
are also other studies that seem to support to some extent the relevance
of microfinance in poverty reduction. Morduch (1999) argues that
microfinance has had positive impact on poverty reduction. However he is keen
to add that “Even in the best of circumstances, credit from microfinance
programs helps fund self employment activities that most often supplement
income for borrowers rather than drive fundamental shifts in employment
patterns. It (microfinance) rarely generates new jobs for others and success has
been especially limited in regions with highly seasonal income patterns and low
population densities (Morduch 1999)”.
No comments:
Post a Comment